Share

Focus on need-based land redistribution system

Tembeka Ngcukaitobi

Land reform under the rule of law seeks to reconcile three intersecting currents: correcting the wrongs of the past, confronting the inequities of the present and securing the future. The state programme for the restitution of land has virtually collapsed. 

Instead of providing a rational point around which previous dispossessions are forgiven, the cutoff point of 19 June 1913 has served to aggravate and perpetrate dispossession. Public funds allocated for the promotion of the public good by paying off the holders of title deeds in exchange for making land available to the descendants of the indigenous people have been misallocated or gone to waste. With the passage of time, records are lost, memories have faded and witnesses are dead. 

Amid the public discontent about the failures of land reform, a sense of prevails among the public representatives. In this context, it must be asked if the achievement of freedom, equality and human dignity through restitution of land can be guaranteed. Here, I offer one possible way out of the quagmire: a need-based land redistribution system.

The redistribution of land to those who need it is emerging as a viable focal point for the advancement of the goal of access to land. And for solid reasons too: while not eschewing historical claims to the land, the redistribution of land connects the past with the present. It recognises that the conquest of the native people of this country was not a single event, characterised by a once-off taking of the land. Rather, it was gradual and totalising in its design. The conquest of the land was supportive of the entire colonial project, concentrated on the extraction of cheap African labour, the destruction of the political autonomy of African communities and the deliberate disruption of African modes of being. 

In sum, the taking of the land was only an instrument in the total cultural, social and economic domination of native peoples. If that legacy is to be undone, the return of the land should be restorative of African humanity. Transactions about the return of the land are incomplete without restoring the dignity of those from whom the land was taken.

But what land should be redistributed? Some commentators have focused on state land. Yet South Africa’s land surface is 121 million hectares. Out of this, only 18 million are state-owned. But importantly about 2% of the land owned by the state is suitable for redistribution. Hence only privately-owned land can address the legacies of the past and undo present inequities. If privately-owned land is the general category, how do we move to the specific? How does the state choose which privately owned land should be earmarked for redistribution to promote the public good?

The moral justification, embodied in our Constitution, for the compulsory taking of private land, still lies in history: if present ownership is owed to a morally questionable acquisition, such as conquest, state interference with private property is justified. But as Robert Nozick suggests in Anarchy, State and Utopia, the primary principled justification for the interference with private property would cease when the historical injustice has been addressed. This proposition itself generates further questions about the type of state he had in mind. How can society right the wrongs of the past without creating new patterns of injustice? 

So, beyond the complexities of history and moral justification, practical questions about the productive use of a limited resource like land must come to the fore. Thus, any redistributive model should start with the premise that land is not infinitely available and is to be productively used for the benefit of society.

But it is also an inheritance for future generations. The priority for the compulsory state taking of land for redistributive purposes must be the private holders not currently using it productively. Specific categories can be developed to carry this out. Farmland lying fallow, hijacked buildings and abandoned buildings fit the class of properties in the category. But the important point is that the justification for the compulsory taking of the land is its non-productive holding. Reversing structural inequality is not only about access, but also includes the use of the land.

Although state land is scarce, some land is held indirectly by the state in various forms such as communal land under the custodianship of traditional leaders. There is controversy about the redistribution of communal land. But we should recall that the Constitution mandates the state to take measures to foster conditions to enable citizens to gain access to land on an equitable
basis. 

Furthermore, the colonial state was characterised by the lack of tenure security of Africans. A key mode in this connection was the reorganisation of the political administration of black communities into tribal areas, native yards and bantu reserves. In each of these, political control was entrenched in the hands of government-selected tribal overlords, who owed no allegiance to the people but to the masters who selected them. In Citizen and Subject, Mahmood Mamdani refers to these phenomena as reflective of a bifurcated state and the indirect rule of Africans.

The white colonial state was for citizens, with its own rules of government, lording over African subjects, who were governed in terms of a European mode of customary law. The Constitution was intended to reverse this by recasting the relationship between African communities, their chiefs and the land. Thus, for redistribution to succeed, it should uproot the colonial state and its surviving tentacles: the people, not the chiefs, should control the land.

While communal land provides a measure of tenure security, tenure over urban land is much more precarious. World Bank studies (which ones cite the studies in the reference) show an urbanisation rate of more than 60% in South Africa in the past 20 years. The message is clear: the pure agrarian society in South Africa has been disrupted irrevocably. Access to rural or farm land will therefore not satisfy land hunger. Urban land must be factored into the frame. But the term urban land might require some unpacking. If we apply the ANC’s Ready to Govern document of 1992, recognition was given first to acquisition of land. The state, it was stated, should therefore have the power to acquire land in a variety of ways, including expropriation.

Yet, expropriation could not be the sole means of land acquisition. Other policy instruments, including land taxes which, if correctly applied, could have the effect of land being freed for redistribution were to be considered. Land taxes are no longer within current policy thinking, which has tended to focus narrowly on acquisition through expropriation. However, land acquisition strategy can be undermined through the loss of extant rights to the land. Popular wisdom suggests that land occupations detract from an orderly programme of land reform.

But experience shows that often land occupations by the poor and the marginalised can facilitate a radical land reform programme, if handled with sensitivity and due care. Domestic laws already validate unlawful land occupations where justice and equity demand. By extending the notion of justice and equity to situations of genuine need for land and proven state failures to avail alternative land, hundreds of unlawful occupiers could be brought within the protective ambit of legislation such as the Prevention of Illegal Eviction from and Unlawful Occupation of Land Act of 1997. The state should recognise that eviction is not always the answer to unlawful land occupation resettlement often provides the correct, constitutionally sound answer.

But a state such as ours can neither encourage land occupations nor depend on them for land reform. Proactive action is mandated by the Constitution. But where to start? As a party in government, the ANC does not start from a blank slate. Its 1992 policy document, Ready to Govern, provides a green light. Four categories of urban land were targeted for redistribution: Land held for speculation; underutilised land or unused land with a productive potential; land which is being degraded; hopelessly indebted land. The precise definitions are, of course, a matter for legislative and statutory expansion, but the point is to identify land categories that may be the target for urban land redistribution without compensation.

A final point must be made. If land reform under the rule of law is about the restoration of African identities lost through conquest, we should interrogate what precisely was lost by conquest. As I have argued elsewhere, land is not the only asset that was lost through colonial occupation. Cattle, farming implements, labour and human potential were taken away. African societies were broken up, their cultures ravaged and their identities erased. The language of restitution or redistribution is too narrow to capture the scope of the project of restoration. A forward-looking project of reparations is urgently needed. What this means is that we need a new way of looking at the future.

Narrow, legalistic conceptions of the meaning of the Constitution must be avoided. An imaginative, expanded and transformative vision of the Constitution and its statutory progenies is needed. Perhaps then reparations through land reform might serve not as colonialism in a different guise, but as an antidote to colonialism. Only then will the land truly be ours.

* This article first appeared in Umrabulo, the ANC's quarterly magazine.

Disclaimer: News24 encourages freedom of speech and the expression of diverse views. The views of columnists published on News24 are therefore their own and do not necessarily represent the views of News24.

We live in a world where facts and fiction get blurred
Who we choose to trust can have a profound impact on our lives. Join thousands of devoted South Africans who look to News24 to bring them news they can trust every day. As we celebrate 25 years, become a News24 subscriber as we strive to keep you informed, inspired and empowered.
Join News24 today
heading
description
username
Show Comments ()
Voting Booth
Should the Proteas pick Faf du Plessis for the T20 World Cup in West Indies and the United States in June?
Please select an option Oops! Something went wrong, please try again later.
Results
Yes! Faf still has a lot to give ...
65% - 169 votes
No! It's time to move on ...
35% - 90 votes
Vote
Rand - Dollar
18.97
+1.3%
Rand - Pound
23.74
+0.9%
Rand - Euro
20.35
+1.0%
Rand - Aus dollar
12.38
+0.8%
Rand - Yen
0.12
+1.4%
Platinum
914.00
+0.2%
Palladium
1,006.50
+0.2%
Gold
2,326.91
+0.5%
Silver
27.38
+0.8%
Brent Crude
88.02
-0.5%
Top 40
68,478
-0.1%
All Share
74,432
-0.1%
Resource 10
61,601
+1.9%
Industrial 25
103,002
-1.0%
Financial 15
15,831
-0.0%
All JSE data delayed by at least 15 minutes Iress logo
Editorial feedback and complaints

Contact the public editor with feedback for our journalists, complaints, queries or suggestions about articles on News24.

LEARN MORE